Most Popular
1. It’s a New Macro, the Gold Market Knows It, But Dead Men Walking Do Not (yet)- Gary_Tanashian
2.Stock Market Presidential Election Cycle Seasonal Trend Analysis - Nadeem_Walayat
3. Bitcoin S&P Pattern - Nadeem_Walayat
4.Nvidia Blow Off Top - Flying High like the Phoenix too Close to the Sun - Nadeem_Walayat
4.U.S. financial market’s “Weimar phase” impact to your fiat and digital assets - Raymond_Matison
5. How to Profit from the Global Warming ClImate Change Mega Death Trend - Part1 - Nadeem_Walayat
7.Bitcoin Gravy Train Trend Forecast 2024 - - Nadeem_Walayat
8.The Bond Trade and Interest Rates - Nadeem_Walayat
9.It’s Easy to Scream Stocks Bubble! - Stephen_McBride
10.Fed’s Next Intertest Rate Move might not align with popular consensus - Richard_Mills
Last 7 days
THEY DON'T RING THE BELL AT THE CRPTO MARKET TOP! - 20th Dec 24
CEREBUS IPO NVIDIA KILLER? - 18th Dec 24
Nvidia Stock 5X to 30X - 18th Dec 24
LRCX Stock Split - 18th Dec 24
Stock Market Expected Trend Forecast - 18th Dec 24
Silver’s Evolving Market: Bright Prospects and Lingering Challenges - 18th Dec 24
Extreme Levels of Work-for-Gold Ratio - 18th Dec 24
Tesla $460, Bitcoin $107k, S&P 6080 - The Pump Continues! - 16th Dec 24
Stock Market Risk to the Upside! S&P 7000 Forecast 2025 - 15th Dec 24
Stock Market 2025 Mid Decade Year - 15th Dec 24
Sheffield Christmas Market 2024 Is a Building Site - 15th Dec 24
Got Copper or Gold Miners? Watch Out - 15th Dec 24
Republican vs Democrat Presidents and the Stock Market - 13th Dec 24
Stock Market Up 8 Out of First 9 months - 13th Dec 24
What Does a Strong Sept Mean for the Stock Market? - 13th Dec 24
Is Trump the Most Pro-Stock Market President Ever? - 13th Dec 24
Interest Rates, Unemployment and the SPX - 13th Dec 24
Fed Balance Sheet Continues To Decline - 13th Dec 24
Trump Stocks and Crypto Mania 2025 Incoming as Bitcoin Breaks Above $100k - 8th Dec 24
Gold Price Multiple Confirmations - Are You Ready? - 8th Dec 24
Gold Price Monster Upleg Lives - 8th Dec 24
Stock & Crypto Markets Going into December 2024 - 2nd Dec 24
US Presidential Election Year Stock Market Seasonal Trend - 29th Nov 24
Who controls the past controls the future: who controls the present controls the past - 29th Nov 24
Gold After Trump Wins - 29th Nov 24
The AI Stocks, Housing, Inflation and Bitcoin Crypto Mega-trends - 27th Nov 24
Gold Price Ahead of the Thanksgiving Weekend - 27th Nov 24
Bitcoin Gravy Train Trend Forecast to June 2025 - 24th Nov 24
Stocks, Bitcoin and Crypto Markets Breaking Bad on Donald Trump Pump - 21st Nov 24
Gold Price To Re-Test $2,700 - 21st Nov 24
Stock Market Sentiment Speaks: This Is My Strong Warning To You - 21st Nov 24
Financial Crisis 2025 - This is Going to Shock People! - 21st Nov 24
Dubai Deluge - AI Tech Stocks Earnings Correction Opportunities - 18th Nov 24
Why President Trump Has NO Real Power - Deep State Military Industrial Complex - 8th Nov 24
Social Grant Increases and Serge Belamant Amid South Africa's New Political Landscape - 8th Nov 24
Is Forex Worth It? - 8th Nov 24
Nvidia Numero Uno in Count Down to President Donald Pump Election Victory - 5th Nov 24
Trump or Harris - Who Wins US Presidential Election 2024 Forecast Prediction - 5th Nov 24
Stock Market Brief in Count Down to US Election Result 2024 - 3rd Nov 24
Gold Stocks’ Winter Rally 2024 - 3rd Nov 24
Why Countdown to U.S. Recession is Underway - 3rd Nov 24
Stock Market Trend Forecast to Jan 2025 - 2nd Nov 24
President Donald PUMP Forecast to Win US Presidential Election 2024 - 1st Nov 24

Market Oracle FREE Newsletter

How to Protect your Wealth by Investing in AI Tech Stocks

Why Hasn't the U.S. Economic Stimulus Been More Stimulative?

Economics / Economic Stimulus Aug 23, 2010 - 06:40 PM GMT

By: Paul_L_Kasriel

Economics

Diamond Rated - Best Financial Markets Analysis ArticleTalk of the economy slipping back into a recession is rampant. The American Recovery and Reconstruction Act (ARRA) of 2009, aka the stimulus package of approximately $790 billion, was, as its title suggests, supposed to put the economy firmly into a recovery trajectory. But as Obama administration economic guru has said, the economy is having trouble reaching recession-escape velocity. Why hasn't the 2009 stimulus package been more stimulative?


For starters, of course, the federal government has been slow in disbursing funds - a genuine case of man bites dog. According to ProPublica.com, as of August 9, $65 billion of the $288 billion of tax cuts, or 23% of the tax cuts, is yet at the disposal of households and businesses. And $230 billion of the $502 billion, or 46% of the allocated spending, still is waiting to be spent. So there still is about 37% of ARRA sitting in the disbursement pipeline.

But I believe that there is a more important reason why ARRA has not been more stimulative in chumming up nominal aggregate demand. I believe that for fiscal policy to stimulate aggregate demand, it needs bank financing. Otherwise, fiscal policy mostly just re-allocates total aggregate demand toward government spending and away from private spending. Let's assume that the federal government increases its spending, financing this via the issuance of additional debt. And let's further assume that this debt is purchased by the nonbank public, including foreign entities. Now, I am going to make a simplifying assumption here by stipulating that the nonbank public cuts back on its current spending, i.e., increases its saving, in order to buy this additional government debt. Under this assumption, total spending in the economy would not increase as a result of the federal government's stimulus program. Rather, private sector current spending would fall by the same amount as government spending increased. An exception to this would be if the nonbank public was willing to rundown its money holdings in order to purchase the increased government debt rather than cut back on current spending. In this exceptional case, total spending could increase. This would be an example of what is referred to an increase in the velocity of money.

In contrast to the nonbank public purchasing the new government debt, if the banking system were to purchase the increase in government debt issued to finance the increase in government spending, then no nonbank entity would have to cut back on its current spending as the government increased its spending. In this case, the fiscal stimulus would stimulate aggregate demand. Government spending would increase without a corresponding decrease in private spending. It is not necessary that the banking system purchase government securities for the fiscal stimulus to stimulate. All that is required is that the banking system increases the total of its holdings of loans and investments by the amount of the increase in government debt. Chart 1 shows that in only one month, July 2010, since the ARRA legislation was signed into law in February 2009 has total bank credit increased. So, if my hypothesis is correct about the relative impotence of fiscal stimulus without corresponding "stimulus" from the banking system, we would not expect ARRA to have had much impact on nominal aggregate demand.

Chart 1

How does fiscal stimulus correlate with growth in nominal aggregate in the U.S.? Not all that well. Plotted in Chart 2 are the Congressional Budget Office's estimates of the cyclically-adjusted federal budget surpluses (+) and deficits (-) as a percent of potential GDP as well as the year-to-year percent change in nominal final sales to domestic purchasers - the aggregate demand concept most likely to be affected by fiscal stimulus. The reason for using the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit is to remove the normal cyclical variations in outlays (unemployment insurance benefit payments, etc) and normal cyclical variations in revenues (corporate tax payments, etc.). The correlation information between the cyclically-adjusted federal budget surplus/deficit and the percent change in nominal final sales to domestic purchasers is shown in the box in the top left-hand corner of Chart 2. A priori, we would expect a negative correlation between the behavior of the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit and the change in nominal aggregate demand. That is, the larger the deficit (a negative number), the larger the percentage increase in nominal aggregate demand growth. And this is just what is indicated by the minus sign in front of the 0.14 in the box. But the "0.14", the correlation coefficient, itself, is problematic for those advocating fiscal stimulus to reboot the economy. The highest possible reading on the correlation coefficient is 1.00, meaning that the two series are perfectly correlated. With the correlation coefficient at only 0.14, the implication is that the cyclically-adjusted surplus/deficit is only weakly correlated. But at least the sign is right!

Chart 2

Chart 3 shows the relationship between the percent change in bank credit (loans and securities on the books of the banking system) and the percent change in nominal final sales to domestic purchasers. A priori, we would expect a positive correlation between the two. And the lack of a minus sign in front of the 0.54 correlation coefficient in the little box in the top left-hand corner of Chart 3 confirms this positive correlation. Notice that the magnitude of the correlation coefficient between bank credit and aggregate demand is much higher than that between the cyclically-adjusted surplus/deficit and aggregate demand.

Chart 3

In order to test for the separate effects on nominal aggregate demand growth of the cyclically-adjusted surplus/deficit and bank credit growth, we have to estimate an ordinary least-squares regression. When we estimate this regression with both explanatory variables included, we are, in effect, asking the following two questions: (1) "What is the effect on nominal aggregate demand growth when the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit changes, holding constant the rate of growth in bank credit?" and (2) "What is the effect on nominal aggregate demand growth when the growth in bank credit changes, holding constant the cyclically-adjusted budget deficit/surplus?"

But first let's run a regression with only the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit as the explanatory variable along with a constant, "c," term. This is shown in Table 1. It would be an understatement to say that the results of this regression would imply the impotency of fiscal policy to stimulate nominal aggregate demand growth. About the best you can say about this regression in terms of the effectiveness of fiscal policy to stimulate nominal aggregate demand growth is that the coefficient has the correct sign in front of it, a minus sign. But the magnitude of the t-statistic, at 0.916 (rounded) suggests the coefficient, or the effect of the cyclically-adjusted deficit as a percent of potential GDP, has a high probability of being zero, nada. Generally, a t-statistic value of 2.00 implies that there is a 95% probability that the value of the coefficient associated with the explanatory variable is different from zero. A minus sign in front of the adjusted R-squared coefficient is never encouraging, along with miniscule size of the coefficient (0.00 rounded, out of a possible maximum of 1.00). In other words, the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit as a percent of potential GDP appears to explain none of the movements in the growth of nominal final sales of domestic purchases.

Table 1

Dependent Variable: Growth in Final Sales to Dom. Purchasers
Method: Least Squares
 
Sample: 1962 2008
Included observations: 47

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Cyclically-Adjusted Deficit as a % of GDP -0.260221 0.284032 -0.916167 0.3645
C 6.850905 0.688854 9.945363 0.0000

R-squared 0.018311 Mean dependent var 7.388511
Adjusted R-squared -0.003504 S.D. dependent var 2.469297
S.E. of regression 2.473620  
Sum squared resid 275.3457  
Log likelihood -108.2353  
F-statistic 0.839363 Durbin-Watson stat 0.551483
Prob(F-statistic) 0.364463  

Now let's run another regression, but this time using only bank credit growth as the explanatory variable along with a constant term. The results of this regression are shown in Table 2. The coefficient on growth in bank credit has the correct sign, positive. The t-statistic value of 4.429 (rounded) indicates that there is more than a 99% probability that the coefficient on bank credit growth is not zero. That is, there is a high probability that bank credit growth affects growth in nominal aggregate demand. The adjusted R-squared coefficient of 0.29 (rounded) is nothing to write home about, but at least is does suggest that growth in bank credit and a constant term do explain some of the variation in the growth of nominal final sales of domestic purchases.

Table 2

Dependent Variable: Growth in Final Sales to Dom. Purchasers
Method: Least Squares
 
Sample: 1962 2008
Included observations: 47

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Growth in Bank Credit 0.454461 0.102609 4.429047 0.0001
C 3.612617 0.905076 3.991508 0.0002

R-squared 0.303583 Mean dependent var 7.388511
Adjusted R-squared 0.288107 S.D. dependent var 2.469297
S.E. of regression 2.083438  
Sum squared resid 195.3322  
Log likelihood -100.1671  
F-statistic 19.61645 Durbin-Watson stat 0.987070
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000060  

Now it is time to run the regression with both the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit as a percent of potential GDP and bank credit growth as explanatory variables, along, of course, with a constant term. The results of this regression are in Table 3. Not surprisingly, the addition of the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit as a percent of potential GDP adds nothing to the explanation of the variation in the growth of nominal final sales to domestic purchasers as evidenced by the same rounded value for the adjusted R-squared coefficient, 0.29, as was the case shown in Table 2. The t-statistic associated with the coefficient on the cyclically-adjusted budget surplus/deficit did increase to -1.084 (rounded), but still remained well short of the "magic" value of "2.0."

Table 3

Dependent Variable: Growth in Final Sales to Dom. Purchasers
Method: Least Squares
 
Sample: 1962 2008
Included observations: 47

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Cyclically-Adjusted Deficit as a % of GDP -0.258822 0.238766 -1.083997 0.2843
Growth in Bank Credit 0.454314 0.102410 4.436217 0.0001
C 3.079121 1.028692 2.993240 0.0045

R-squared 0.321697 Mean dependent var 7.388511
Adjusted R-squared 0.290866 S.D. dependent var 2.469297
S.E. of regression 2.079398  
Sum squared resid 190.2514  
Log likelihood -99.54778  
F-statistic 10.43391 Durbin-Watson stat 0.986171
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000196  

Notice that in the bottom right-hand corner of Table 3 (Tables 1 and 2, also) there is something called the "Durbin-Watson stat(istic)" with a value of 0.986 (rounded). When the value of the Durbin-Watson statistic is less than 2.0, this generally indicates the presence of something called serial correlation. This means that the current observation of the dependent variable, in this case, growth in final sales to domestic purchasers, tends to be associated with prior observations of itself. When serial correlation is indicated, then the values of the coefficients on the independent variables are susceptible to bias. In order to correct for serial correlation, we ran the regression with a first-order auto-regressive correction. The results of this regression are shown in Table 4. After this correction for serial correlation, the qualitative results from Table 3 did not change. All the signs on the coefficients were what would be expected a priori, there remains a high probability that the coefficient on the bank credit growth explanatory variable is not zero and there is a higher probability that the coefficient on fiscal policy explanatory variable is zero. There is a high probability that the coefficient on the first-order auto-regressive adjustment is different from zero (with a t-statistic value of 5.907 (rounded). Moreover, the first-order auto-regressive adjustment has removed the potential bias of serial correlation inasmuch as the Durbin-Watson statistic is 2.110 (rounded). With the correction for serial correlation, the "explanatory" power of the variation in the growth of final sales to domestic purchasers is boosted, as evidenced by the increase in the adjusted R-squared coefficient by 25 basis points or by 86%.

Table 4

Dependent Variable: Growth in Final Sales to Dom. Purchasers
Method: Least Squares
 
Sample (adjusted): 1963 2008
Included observations: 46 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 9 iterations

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Cyclically-Adjusted Deficit as a % of GDP -0.426573 0.294055 -1.450657 0.1543
Growth in Bank Credit 0.185636 0.082474 2.250851 0.0297
C 4.718627 1.236691 3.815527 0.0004
First -Order Auto- Regressive Adj. 0.708254 0.119905 5.906800 0.0000

R-squared 0.573282 Mean dependent var 7.392826
Adjusted R-squared 0.542802 S.D. dependent var 2.496403
S.E. of regression 1.687978  
Sum squared resid 119.6693  
Log likelihood -87.26126  
F-statistic 18.80857 Durbin-Watson stat 2.110544
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000  

The upshot of all this analysis is that fiscal stimulus unaccompanied by bank credit growth appears to be impotent. Given that bank credit has been contracting through most of the period that ARRA has been operative, the deck was stacked against the success of this fiscal policy action to increase the growth in the nominal aggregate from the outset. The analysis above suggests that if faster growth in nominal aggregate demand is desired, policymakers should concentrate more on invigorating bank credit growth and, if for capital-adequacy reasons the banking system cannot put more assets on its collective balance sheet, the central bank could create credit for the nonbank system more directly.

The analysis does not necessarily rule out a role for fiscal stimulus in increasing nominal aggregate demand. If private credit demand is weakening, then one avenue to invigorate bank credit growth would be for the federal government to become the "borrower of last resort" through increased spending and/or tax cuts. Again, if because of capital constraints the commercial banking system were not in a position to increase its net credit creation by the amount of the increased government borrowing, then the central bank could create the requisite credit directly. This is exactly what then Princeton professor Benjamin Bernanke recommended in a paper ("Japanese Monetary Policy: A Case of Self-Induced Paralysis?") presented at the ASSA meeting in December 1999 that the Japanese Diet and the Bank of Japan do to bring the Japanese economy out of its deflationary stupor.

by Paul Kasriel

Paul Kasriel is the recipient of the 2006 Lawrence R. Klein Award for Blue Chip Forecasting Accuracy

by Paul Kasriel
The Northern Trust Company
Economic Research Department - Daily Global Commentary

Copyright © 2010 Paul Kasriel
Paul joined the economic research unit of The Northern Trust Company in 1986 as Vice President and Economist, being named Senior Vice President and Director of Economic Research in 2000. His economic and interest rate forecasts are used both internally and by clients. The accuracy of the Economic Research Department's forecasts has consistently been highly-ranked in the Blue Chip survey of about 50 forecasters over the years. To that point, Paul received the prestigious 2006 Lawrence R. Klein Award for having the most accurate economic forecast among the Blue Chip survey participants for the years 2002 through 2005.

The opinions expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of The Northern Trust Company. The Northern Trust Company does not warrant the accuracy or completeness of information contained herein, such information is subject to change and is not intended to influence your investment decisions.

Paul L. Kasriel Archive

© 2005-2022 http://www.MarketOracle.co.uk - The Market Oracle is a FREE Daily Financial Markets Analysis & Forecasting online publication.


Comments

T. R. Smith
31 Oct 10, 08:47
Bank credit

Excellent comment which tends to provide empirical support for the point made by Alvin Hansen in his "Guide to Keynes," when he is discussing R. Kahn's leakages to the employment multiplier. Not enough has been said about this and trade imbalances as well as the use of stimulus to reduce household debt.


jonnysingapore
01 Nov 10, 16:20
not clear

Paul, you are an exception analyst always with detailed technical backups to your arguments.

However this didnt make sense to me. Your para before chart 1 says,

'if the banking system purchases the debt.....[no reduction in private consumption]' but you then go on to say

'the banking system DOESNT have to buy the debt, just increase its loans and investments...'

If so, who buys the government debt? If the banking system doesnt and it comes out of nonbank public, then consumpion funds are reduced.

Sorry, I didnt follow your thinking.


Post Comment

Only logged in users are allowed to post comments. Register/ Log in